Скачать презентацию Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring Скачать презентацию Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring

293219356fd4b5386757280784074d40.ppt

  • Количество слайдов: 50

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 12 Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 12

Contract law so far w What is a contract? Why do we need them? Contract law so far w What is a contract? Why do we need them? w Which contracts should be enforced? w Breach of contract. What should happen? Can we design law to get efficient amount of breach? w Reliance investments. Can we design law to get efficient amount of reliance investments? w Default rules. Two views of how to use default rules to increase efficiency. w This week: when should contracts not be enforced? 1

When should a contract not be enforced? 2 When should a contract not be enforced? 2

When should voluntary trade not be allowed? w Going back to property law… Coase When should voluntary trade not be allowed? w Going back to property law… Coase Theorem: to get efficient outcomes, we should let people trade whenever they want to w But also saw some exceptions – some trades that aren’t, and shouldn’t, be allowed w Selling enriched uranium to a terrorist w w Similarly with contract law… First day: to get efficient outcomes, enforce any contract both parties wanted enforced w But next, we’ll see exceptions – contracts which shouldn’t be enforced, due to externalities or market failures/transaction costs w 3

Discussion question w “For efficiency, enforce any contract which both the promisor and the Discussion question w “For efficiency, enforce any contract which both the promisor and the promisee wanted to be enforceable when it was signed” 4

Example of an unenforceable contract: a contract which breaks the law w Obvious: contract Example of an unenforceable contract: a contract which breaks the law w Obvious: contract to buy a kilo of cocaine is unenforceable 5

Example of an unenforceable contract: a contract which breaks the law w Obvious: contract Example of an unenforceable contract: a contract which breaks the law w Obvious: contract to buy a kilo of cocaine is unenforceable w Less obvious: otherwise-legal contract whose real purpose is to circumvent a law Legal doctrine: derogation of public policy w Derogate, verb. detract from; curtail application of (a law) w Applies to contracts which could only be performed by breaking law… w …but also to “innocent” contracts whose purpose is to get around a law or regulation w 6

Derogation of public policy – example w Labor unions required by law to negotiate Derogation of public policy – example w Labor unions required by law to negotiate “in good faith” w Recent NBA labor troubles Old CBA: 57% of “basketball-related income” went to player salaries w Owners were offering less than 50%, players demanding 53%. . . w Imagine the following contract: w “For the next 50 years, if the NBAPA accepts a CBA paying less than 55% of BRI in player salaries, then we also agree that all non-retired players will work for you as coal miners every offseason at federal minimum wage. ” Purpose is purely to “bind hands” in negotiations with ownership w Contract would not be enforced w 7

Derogation of public policy w In general: a contract is not enforceable if it Derogation of public policy w In general: a contract is not enforceable if it cannot be performed without breaking the law w Exception: if promisor knew (and promisee didn’t) I’m married, my girlfriend in California doesn’t know; I promise her I’ll marry her, she quits her job and moves to Madison w My company agrees to supply a product that we can’t produce without violating a safety or environmental regulation w Keeping either promise would require breaking the law… w …but I’d still be liable for damages for breach w w Like in Ayres and Gertner: default rule penalizes betterinformed party for withholding information 8

Default rules versus regulations w Talked earlier about default rules Default rules apply if Default rules versus regulations w Talked earlier about default rules Default rules apply if no other rule is specified… w …but can be contracted around w w Rules like “derogation of public policy” cannot be contracted around Parties to a contract can’t say, “even though this type of contract would normally not be valid, this one is” w Rules which always apply: immutable rules, or mandatory rules, or regulations w w Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules and regulations. 9

Ways to get out of a contract 10 Ways to get out of a contract 10

Formation Defenses and Performance Excuses w Formation defense Claim that a valid contract does Formation Defenses and Performance Excuses w Formation defense Claim that a valid contract does not exist w (Example: no consideration) w w Performance excuse Yes, a valid contract was created w But circumstances have changed and I should be allowed to not perform without penalty w w Most doctrines for invalidating a contract can be explained as either… Individuals agreeing to the contract were not rational, or w Transaction cost or market failure w 11

One formation defense: incompetence w Courts will not enforce contracts with people who can’t One formation defense: incompetence w Courts will not enforce contracts with people who can’t be presumed to be rational Children w Legally insane w w Incompetence One party was “not competent to enter into the agreement” w No “meeting of the minds” w 12

So… w If courts won’t enforce a contract signed by someone who wasn’t competent… So… w If courts won’t enforce a contract signed by someone who wasn’t competent… w What if you signed a contract while drunk? You need to have been really, really drunk to get out of a contract w (“Intoxicated to the extent of being unable to comprehend the nature and consequences of the instrument he executed”) w Lucy v. Zehmer, Virginia Sup Ct 1954 w 13

Lucy v. Zehmer w Zehmer and his wife owned a farm (“the Ferguson farm”), Lucy v. Zehmer w Zehmer and his wife owned a farm (“the Ferguson farm”), Lucy had been trying to buy it for some time w While out drinking, Lucy offers $50, 000, Zehmer responds, “You don’t have $50, 000” w “We hereby agree to sell to W. O. Lucy the Ferguson Farm complete for $50, 00000, title satisfactory to buyer. ” 14

Lucy v. Zehmer w Zehmer and his wife owned a farm (“the Ferguson farm”), Lucy v. Zehmer w Zehmer and his wife owned a farm (“the Ferguson farm”), Lucy had been trying to buy it for some time w While out drinking, Lucy offers $50, 000, Zehmer responds, “You don’t have $50, 000” w “We hereby agree to sell to W. O. Lucy the Ferguson Farm complete for $50, 00000, title satisfactory to buyer. ” 15

Lucy v. Zehmer w So, you can be pretty drunk and still be bound Lucy v. Zehmer w So, you can be pretty drunk and still be bound by the contract you signed Might think “meeting of the minds” would be impossible w But imagine what would happen if the rule went the other way w 16

Lucy v. Zehmer w So, you can be pretty drunk and still be bound Lucy v. Zehmer w So, you can be pretty drunk and still be bound by the contract you signed Might think “meeting of the minds” would be impossible w But imagine what would happen if the rule went the other way w w Borat lawsuits w Julie Hilden, “Borat Sequel: Legal Proceedings Against Not Kazahk Journalist for Make Benefit Guileless Americans In Film” w Moral of the story: don’t get drunk with people who might ask you to sign a contract 17

Another formation defense: dire constraints 18 Another formation defense: dire constraints 18

Dire constraints w Necessity I’m about to starve, someone offers me a sandwich for Dire constraints w Necessity I’m about to starve, someone offers me a sandwich for $10, 000 w My boat’s about to sink, someone offers me a ride to shore for $1, 000 w Contract would not be upheld: I signed it out of necessity w w Duress Other party is responsible for situation I’m in w “I made him an offer he couldn’t refuse” w Contract signed at gunpoint would not be legally enforceable w 19

Duress source: http: //news. yahoo. com/man-sues-former-hostages-saysbroke-promise-190902970. html 20 Duress source: http: //news. yahoo. com/man-sues-former-hostages-saysbroke-promise-190902970. html 20

Friedman on duress w Example Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him Friedman on duress w Example Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him $100 w You write him a check w Do you have to honor the agreement? w w “Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both parties wanted it to be enforceable” He did – he wants your $100 w You did – you’d rather pay $100 than be killed w w So why not enforce it? Makes muggings more profitable leads to more muggings w Tradeoff: refuse to enforce a Pareto-improving trade, in order to avoid incentive for bad behavior w 21

Friedman on duress w Example Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him Friedman on duress w Example Mugger threatens to kill you unless you give him $100 w You write him a check w Do you have to honor the agreement? w w “Efficiency requires enforcing a contract if both parties wanted it to be enforceable” He did – he wants your $100 w You did – you’d rather pay $100 than be killed w w So why not enforce it? Makes muggings more profitable leads to more muggings w Tradeoff: refuse to enforce a Pareto-improving trade, in order to avoid incentive for bad behavior w 22

What about necessity? w Same logic doesn’t work for necessity You get caught in What about necessity? w Same logic doesn’t work for necessity You get caught in a storm on your $10, 000 sailboat w Tugboat offers to tow you to shore for $9, 000 w (Otherwise he’ll save your life but let your boat sink) w w Duress: if we enforce contract, incentive for more crimes w w w Here: if we enforce contract, incentive for more tugboats to be available for rescues – why is that bad? Social benefit of rescue: value of boat, minus cost of tow Say, $10, 000 – $10, 000 = $9, 990, 000 If tugboat gets entire value, his private gain = social gain So tugboat captain would invest the efficient amount in being available to rescue you So what’s the problem? 23

What about necessity? w What about your decision: whether to sail that day w What about necessity? w What about your decision: whether to sail that day w w w w w 1 in 1000 chance of being caught in a storm If so, 1 in 2 that a tugboat will rescue you Private cost of sailing: 1 in 2000 you lose boat, 1 in 2000 you pay tugboat captain value of boat $10, 000/2000 + $10, 000/2000 = $10, 000 So you’ll choose to sail if your value is above $10, 000 Social cost: 1 in 2000 boat is lost, 1 in 2000 boat is rescued $10, 000/2000 + $10, 000/2000 = $5, 005 Efficient to sail when your value is above $5, 005 When your value from sailing is between $5, 005 and $10, 000, you “undersail” If the price of being towed was just the marginal cost, your private cost = social cost and you would sail the efficient amount 24

Friedman’s point w Same transaction sets incentives on both parties w Price that would Friedman’s point w Same transaction sets incentives on both parties w Price that would be efficient for one decision, is inefficient for other w “Put the incentive where it would do the most good” Least inefficient price is somewhere in the middle w And probably not the price that would be negotiated in the middle of a storm! w 25

Friedman’s point w Same transaction sets incentives on both parties w Price that would Friedman’s point w Same transaction sets incentives on both parties w Price that would be efficient for one decision, is inefficient for other w “Put the incentive where it would do the most good” Least inefficient price is somewhere in the middle w And probably not the price that would be negotiated in the middle of a storm! w So makes sense for courts to overturn contracts signed under necessity, replace them with ex-ante optimal terms w w More general point Single price creates multiple incentives w May be impossible to get efficient behavior in all dimensions w 26

Real duress versus fake duress w Court won’t enforce contracts signed under threat of Real duress versus fake duress w Court won’t enforce contracts signed under threat of harm w “Give me $100 or I’ll shoot you” w But many negotiations contain threats “Give me a raise, or I’ll quit” w “$3, 000 is my final offer for the car, take it or I walk” w w The difference? Threat of destruction of value versus failure to create value w A promise is enforceable if extracted as price of cooperating in creating value; not if it was extracted by threat to destroy value w 27

Example: Alaska Packers’ Association v Domenico (US Ct App 1902) w Captain hires crew Example: Alaska Packers’ Association v Domenico (US Ct App 1902) w Captain hires crew in Seattle for fishing expedition to Alaska w In Alaska, crew demands higher wages or they’ll quit, captain agrees w Back in Seattle, captain refuses to pay the higher wages, claiming he agreed to them under duress w Court ruled for captain w Since crew had already agreed to do the work, no new consideration was given for promise of higher wage 28

A performance excuse: impossibility 29 A performance excuse: impossibility 29

Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility w When performance becomes impossible, should promisor Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility w When performance becomes impossible, should promisor owe damages, or be excused from performing? w A perfect contract would explicitly state who bears each risk w Contract may give clues as to how gaps should be filled w Industry custom might be clear w But in some cases, court must fill gap 30

Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility w In most situations, when neither contract Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility w In most situations, when neither contract nor industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held liable for breach w But there are exceptions w Change “destroyed a basic assumption on which the contract was made” 31

Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility w In most situations, when neither contract Next doctrine for voiding a contract: impossibility w In most situations, when neither contract nor industry norm offers guidance, promisor is held liable for breach w But there are exceptions w Change “destroyed a basic assumption on which the contract was made” w Efficiency requires assigning liability to the party that can bear the risk at least cost w How to determine who that is? 32

Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? w Friedman offers several bases Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? w Friedman offers several bases for making this determination Spreading losses across many transactions w Moral hazard: who is in better position to influence outcome? w 33

Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? w Friedman offers several bases Who is the efficient bearer of a particular risk? w Friedman offers several bases for making this determination Spreading losses across many transactions w Moral hazard: who is in better position to influence outcome? w Adverse selection: who is more aware of risk, even if he can’t do anything about it? w w “…The party with control over some part of the production process is in a better position both to prevent losses and to predict them. It follows that an efficient contract will usually assign the loss associated with something going wrong to the party with control over that particular something. ” 34

That’s why Hadley v Baxendale was “surprising” w Baxendale (shipper) could influence speed of That’s why Hadley v Baxendale was “surprising” w Baxendale (shipper) could influence speed of delivery, Hadley could not w So Baxendale was efficient bearer of the risk of delay w Court ruled he didn’t owe damages for lost profits, forcing Hadley to bear much of this risk Only makes sense as a “penalty default” w Rule creates incentive for Hadley to reveal urgency of this shipment w 35

Hadley v Baxendale w Suppose… 80% of millers are low-damage – suffer $100 in Hadley v Baxendale w Suppose… 80% of millers are low-damage – suffer $100 in losses from delay w 20% of millers are high-damage – suffer $200 in losses from delay w w Shipper liable for actual damages Average miller would suffer $120 in losses w Shipper makes efficient investment for average type w But not efficient for either type w w Shipper liable foreseeable damages Shipper makes efficient investment for low-damage millers w High-damage millers have strong incentive to negotiate around default rule w 36

Contracts based on bad information (may not get to this) 37 Contracts based on bad information (may not get to this) 37

Contracts based on faulty information w Four doctrines for invalidating a contract w Fraud Contracts based on faulty information w Four doctrines for invalidating a contract w Fraud w Failure to disclose w Frustration of purpose w Mutual mistake 38

Fraud w Fraud: one party was deliberately tricked source: http: //www. wyff 4. com/r/29030818/detail. Fraud w Fraud: one party was deliberately tricked source: http: //www. wyff 4. com/r/29030818/detail. html 39

What if you trick someone by withholding information? w Under the civil law, there What if you trick someone by withholding information? w Under the civil law, there is a duty to disclose w If you fail to supply information you should have, contract will be voided – failure to disclose w Less so under the common law Seller only has to share information about hidden dangers… w …not information that makes a product less valuable but not dangerous w Exception: new products come with “implied warranty of fitness” w Another exception: Obde v Schlemeyer w 40

Duty to disclose under common law w Under common law, seller required to inform Duty to disclose under common law w Under common law, seller required to inform buyer about hidden safety risks, generally not other information w But… Obde v Schlemeyer (1960, Sup Ct of WA) w Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer w Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent further damage w Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose (awarded damages) w 41

Duty to disclose under common law w Under common law, seller required to inform Duty to disclose under common law w Under common law, seller required to inform buyer about hidden safety risks, generally not other information w But… w w w Obde v Schlemeyer (1960, Sup Ct of WA) Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent further damage Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose (awarded damages) Some states require used car dealers to reveal major repairs done, sellers of homes to reveal certain types of defects… 42

What if both parties were misinformed? Frustration of Purpose w Change in circumstance made What if both parties were misinformed? Frustration of Purpose w Change in circumstance made the original promise pointless w Coronation Cases w “When a contingency makes performance pointless, assign liability to party who can bear risk at least cost” 43

What if both parties were misinformed? Frustration of Purpose w Change in circumstance made What if both parties were misinformed? Frustration of Purpose w Change in circumstance made the original promise pointless Mutual Mistake w Mutual mistake about facts w Coronation Cases w “When a contingency makes performance pointless, assign liability to party who can bear risk at least cost” w Circumstances had already changed, but we didn’t know Logger buys land with timber on it, but forest fire had wiped out the timber the week before Mutual mistake about identity Disagreement over what was being sold 44

Another principle for allocating risks efficiently: uniting knowledge and control w Hadley v Baxendale Another principle for allocating risks efficiently: uniting knowledge and control w Hadley v Baxendale (miller and shipper) Hadley knew shipment was time-critical w But Baxendale was deciding how to ship crankshaft (boat or train) w Party that had information was not the party making decisions w w Efficiency generally requires uniting knowledge and control Contracts that unite knowledge and control are generally efficient, should be upheld w Contracts that separate knowledge and control may be inefficient, should more often be set aside w 45

Mutual vs. Unilateral Mistake w Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information w Contract Mutual vs. Unilateral Mistake w Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information w Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control w Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless w You sell it to me at a low price w w Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld 46

Unilateral mistake w Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information w Contract neither united Unilateral mistake w Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information w Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control w Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless w You sell it to me at a low price w w Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld Contracts based on unilateral mistake generally unite knowledge and control w And, enforcing them creates an incentive to gather information w 47

Unilateral mistake: Laidlaw v Organ (U. S. Supreme Court, 1815) w War of 1812: Unilateral mistake: Laidlaw v Organ (U. S. Supreme Court, 1815) w War of 1812: British blockaded port of New Orleans w Price of tobacco fell, since it couldn’t be exported w Organ (tobacco buyer) learned the war was over w Immediately negotiated with Laidlaw firm to buy a bunch of tobacco at the depressed wartime price w Next day, news broke the war had ended, price of tobacco went up, Laidlaw sued w Supreme Court ruled that Organ was not required to communicate his information 48

Unilateral mistake: productive versus redistributive information w Productive information: information that can be used Unilateral mistake: productive versus redistributive information w Productive information: information that can be used to produce more wealth w Redistributive information: information that can be used to redistribute wealth in favor of informed party w Cooter and Ulen Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of productive information should be enforced… w …especially if that knowledge was the result of active investment w Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of purely redistributive information, or fortuitously acquired information, should not be enforced w 49